Money: Free and Unfree: The Independent Review: The Independent ... [PDF]

Restrictions on branching and the requirement that commercial banks hold treasury bonds as reserves do more to explain t

2 downloads 18 Views 194KB Size

Recommend Stories


2017 Independent Intelligence Review
Don’t grieve. Anything you lose comes round in another form. Rumi

Independent Review of the ICANN Nominating Committee
We can't help everyone, but everyone can help someone. Ronald Reagan

Independent Review of the Financial Ombudsman Service
It always seems impossible until it is done. Nelson Mandela

THE INDEPENDENT P resident
When you talk, you are only repeating what you already know. But if you listen, you may learn something

The Independent News
You have to expect things of yourself before you can do them. Michael Jordan

The Independent Scholar
Don’t grieve. Anything you lose comes round in another form. Rumi

The Independent Depositary Bank
Do not seek to follow in the footsteps of the wise. Seek what they sought. Matsuo Basho

The Berkshire Independent Hospital
You often feel tired, not because you've done too much, but because you've done too little of what sparks

Independent Integrity Unit, and the Independent Redress Mechanism
Where there is ruin, there is hope for a treasure. Rumi

The President and the Independent Counsel
Don't ruin a good today by thinking about a bad yesterday. Let it go. Anonymous

Idea Transcript


Volume 22 Number 3 • Winter 2018 Subscribe



Buy Single Issues



Get the App

Other Issues: Volume 22 Number 3 • Winter 2018

Book Title: Money: Free and Unfree Author:

By George Selgin

Published: Washington D.C.: Cato Institute. Price:

$24.95 (Hardcover) $11.99 (Kindle)

Pages:

Pp. xiii, 379.

Reviewer:

Nicolás Cachanosky

This book review appeared in the Winter 2018 issue of The Independent Review

George Selgin has made a career, and a name, by asking and answering uncomfortable questions in the realm of monetary history and policy. Selgin’s contributions rest in questioning priors that most policymakers and fellow monetary economists hold without giving a second thought. Questioning priors is a significant way of making scientific process because it expands the borders of our understanding. In Money: Free and Unfree, the reader gets a glance at some of the most relevant contributions by Selgin in roughly the last three decades. Two challenges to monetary conventional wisdom underlie the whole book. First, central banks are in fact a source of financial instability and cannot (at least certainly not easily) outperform a free market of money and banking (i.e. free banking). Second, fractional reserve banking itself, and therefore banks, are not inherently unstable. This means that there is no need of a supervising body such as a central bank. Fractional reserve banking may be a channel through which a crisis spreads, but is not the source of the crisis. Rather, the source of the crisis is to be found in central banks and financial regulations. The book is divided in three sections. Part I is about the regulatory sources of financial instability. Part II discusses the monetary and banking situation in the U.S. before the Federal Reserve. And Part III is about the Federal Reserve era. Part I is particularly timely since the effects of the 2008 crisis are still being felt. As soon as something goes wrong in the economy, then the default position by policymakers and the median voter is for the government to fix it. To fix the economy has a specific meaning, which is that the government needs to revise and increase regulations. The government doing more, rather than less, is the default position when it comes to money and banking. Selgin shows how the outcome of financial regulation is the opposite of its intention. Financial regulation contributes to, if it is not a cause itself of, financial instability. For instance, the last housing and financial crisis cannot be understood without a proper knowledge of how housing and financial regulation unintendedly colluded to produce a housing bubble. Selgin’s argument implies that central banks do not only historically rise to serve fiscal needs, but their own presence is a source of financial instability. The problem is that the presence of a central bank means there is no longer a free and unregulated market of money and banking in place. Central banks do not just regulate the market of money and banking, central banks need to replace the market forces of money and banking. Paraphrasing Friedrich Hayek, this requires quite a pretense of knowledge on part of policymakers. But it is questionable that central bankers have access to the required knowledge regardless of their technical expertise. Central bankers need replace no less of a complex system than the “invisible hand” in money and banking. This is a challenge that most economists would deny they are able to do in any given market, but for some reason it becomes an unquestioned truth in the much more complex market of money and banking. Rather than accepting this asymmetry, Selgin takes the scholarly position of challenging how much monetary policy and financial regulation can actually do. Can Selgin’s claims be backed? They can. One way is to study how historical cases of free banking actually performed rather than how formal models that start with the assumption of inherent banking instability assume free banking would work. While this is not the main topic of this book, discussions of main issues on this topic are not lacking throughout the book. Other discussions are more upfront in this text. For instance, another way to support Selgin’s arguments is to show that financial crises before the Federal Reserve were due to ill-designed regulation and the outcome of fiscal policies. Restrictions on branching and the requirement that commercial banks hold treasury bonds as reserves do more to explain the pre-Fed financial crisis than picturesque wildcat banking stories and the assumption that banks are unstable. More empirical evidence supporting Selgin’s arguments is not far away. Selgin shows how Canada challenges the idea that free banking cannot accommodate money supply to money demand and self-contain bank failures. In fact, it can be argued that Canada without a central bank had more financial stability than the United States with the Federal Reserve. The lesson from this comparison is that United State would likely been better imitating Canada’s monetary regime than founding the Federal Reserve. There is yet another way to back Selgin’s claims, which consists in not falling for the Nirvana fallacy. Namely, to compare real central banks, rather than ideal but nonexistent central banks, to real alternative monetary regimes. It is as easy and convenient as inappropriate to conclude that an ideal central bank can outperform a real world free banking regime. However, the relevant and interesting question is whether or not real central banks do outperform alternative monetary regimes. Chapter 8 shows, quite convincingly, that after a century the Federal Reserve has been unable to outperform the pre-Fed banking regime in the U.S. This result holds even after discounting the early “learning years” of the Fed. It is also interesting to note that this exercise shows that the Fed even underperforms a monetary regime that is far away from being a true free banking regime. Notwithstanding this situation, neither policymakers nor monetary economists even consider raising the question of what monetary reform can improve financial stability. Textbooks are flooded with what central banks can ideally do. But ink is rarely spared in discussing alternative monetary regimes. Selgin’s work calls attention to a massive confirmation bias problem. Starting with the unquestioned assumption that banking is inherently unstable, formal models are designed in a way that would predict financial crisis. Then, historical cases of financial crisis are used to empirically support such models. This empirical support has two problems though. First, these cases do not represent free banking scenarios, but regulated scenarios. It cannot be concluded, then, that banks are inherently unstable. It is inaccurate and misleading, for instance, to refer to the U.S. pre-Fed era as a case of free banking. Second, the empirical evidence is incomplete. By only looking at failed cases of financial regulation, we are unintentionally choosing data that matches the priors of the models. A number of historical cases of free banking (Canada, Scotland, and Australia to just mention a few) show that money and banking can self-regulate. A significant part of the economic profession, however, seems to ignore this historical evidence rather than revise and question the models and priors of financial instability. As Selgin (p. ix) argues, “the surprising truth is that most economists, including most champions of the monetary status quo (or something not far from it) are only vaguely familiar with alternative arrangements, assuming that they are aware of them at all.” Monetary history is an area where the average economist is not well informed. Selgin’s Money: Free and Unfree, is required reading for any scholar who wants to go beyond holding unquestioned premises. Nicolás Cachanosky Metropolitan State University of Denver Buy Money: Free and Unfree at Amazon.com for $24.95 (Hardcover) Buy Money: Free and Unfree at Amazon.com for $11.99 (Kindle) Independent Review Issues Vol. 22 Num. 3 - Winter 2018

Independent Review Articles by Subject Articles Indexed By Subject

The Independent Review Home A Word from the Publisher Editors’ Welcome What Others Are Saying about The Independent Review Recommend The Independent Review To Your Local Library Advertise in The Independent Review Abstractors and Indexers Instructions for Manuscript Submission Staff and Editorial Board Policies

Smile Life

When life gives you a hundred reasons to cry, show life that you have a thousand reasons to smile

Get in touch

© Copyright 2015 - 2024 PDFFOX.COM - All rights reserved.